Global public investment: a critique

23 October 2023

What I like about many discussions on development cooperation (especially official development assistance or ODA) is the reflection on issues of perverse incentives, risks of instrumentalising development cooperation for non-developmental purposes, and the decreasing integrity of the ODA reporting system.

In recent years, there has been a debate on so-called “global public investment” or GPI. This discussion is largely motivated by criticism of ODA (often referred to as “foreign aid” by GPI proponents in this context) and proposes a different approach to international cooperation: it is described as a new approach to concessional international public finance for sustainable development – available to everyone.

The ambition of GPI to improve international cooperation seems perfectly fine. However, it is rather difficult to find any reflections on the possible limitations of GPI. Yes, in a political campaign you probably don’t start with what could be wrong with your proposal. Nonetheless, I need to understand it if I am not just sympathetic to the motivation of a concept, but think it is something I should really support.

In this regard, I have some fundamental concerns about GPI. I believe it presents a distorted representation of ODA; a high level of vagueness; and a lack of integration of real-world constraints.

GPI paints a misleading picture of ODA. For example, GPI advocates claim that ODA has a narrow focus on reducing poverty, whereas GPI would be geared to meeting broader challenges of inequality and sustainability. This assertion ignores the fact that many ODA actors are not just focused on poverty reduction. It is just a wrong perception of what ODA is about – at least for a majority of actors in this field. ODA has been tackling inequality and sustainability for many decades. The link between ODA and the provision of global public goods (GPGs) is long-standing. We know that there has always been a proportion of GPGs financed by ODA – and this proportion is increasing, not least because of climate finance. Unfortunately, the reality is complex and we must increasingly address the question of the extent to which ODA-funded GPGs crowd out development objectives that are not related to GPGs.

The fundamentals of GPI are somewhere between naive and vague. Just a few comments on this.

The conceptual relationship between ODA and GPI remains unclear. Even if GPI is not meant to replace ODA (which, by the way, is conceptually not very coherent), it might be difficult to find support for this approach among official actors in the Global South. Looking at the debates on climate finance, it is clear that important and economically powerful countries of the South (from China to Saudi Arabia) reject any requirement that they should be required to contribute to global climate finance funds in this regard. Why would they agree to GPI?

One advantage of ODA is that – compared to other soft areas of international cooperation – it is based on a transparent definition, criteria, a well-established reporting system and even an absolute target for the expected contribution of OECD countries (0.7% of their gross domestic product). This approach is far from perfect. However, ignoring the option that GPI could lead to reduced pressure on the existence of this system would be risky. Some OECD countries might be grateful to GPI if they can get rid of existing ODA obligations.

GPI is supposed to be “a universal effort, with all paying in and all benefitting”. The benefits are defined in terms of public investments. But what about other cooperation modalities like knowledge cooperation (a main modality of South-South cooperation)? The preferred payments are in terms of grants. But what about the advantages of concessional loans, which enable more funds to be mobilised for economically viable projects? On paper everyone benefitting sounds good, but in reality, I do not find a convincing argument why a GPI mechanism should channel grants to Switzerland, United Arab Emirates, North Korea or China.

All the seemingly technical aspects are unclear. Who should contribute and how much? Who can receive what share of the funds? Who should represent the countries in concrete terms? These are not technical questions, but questions of principle. To assume that we can find a solution later does not sound like a well-prepared plan.

In summary, GPI claims to view international cooperation from a broad perspective. In fact, it is largely a critical but simplistic response to the realities of the existing modes of development cooperation. Experience from international climate finance shows how difficult and messy it is to establish a new system of burden sharing. GPI asks us to believe that we should aim to somehow set up such a system for all global public goods. The concept is hardly helpful as a brainstorming exercise and is not very suitable as an approach to politics under real conditions to show possible solutions.

Author/s

Stephan Klingebiel

Stephan Klingebiel is Head of the Inter- and Transnational Cooperation Research Program at the German Institute of Development and Sustainability (IDOS), formerly the German Development Institute. He is also a visiting professor at Ewha Womans University in South Korea, an honorary distinguished fellow at the Centre for Sustainability at Jindal School of Government and Public Policy in India, a senior lecturer at the University of Bonn and a visiting professor at the University of Turin.

Comments

  1. The concept of Global Public Investment is certainly less useful than sometimes advertised as an alternative or successor to the concept of Official Development Assistance. And it works better as an abstract category of international financing than it does as a rallying point for resource mobilisation.

    But GPI need not be and is not always presented as a replacement for ODA; it is sometimes proposed as a complement, with an additionality stipulation. And the requirement for all countries to contribute is separable from the core concept, as we see in the case of various global environment funds.

    GPI suffers from being neither chicken nor egg: the global institutions we have for financing global public goods are almost entirely ODA-funded, which means they are obliged to operate only for the benefit of developing countries and spread their resources more or less according to equitable allocation criteria that work against global impact. For this reason, nobody has yet been able to build an institution that is big enough to fight a global public bad, expert and inclusive enough to win broad-based trust, yet hard-nosed enough to put its money exactly where it will achieve the greatest impact for the world as a whole.

    The new, smaller-than-hoped Pandemic Fund is built along the same lines as many previous climate and health financing vehicles. The formerly ODA-dependent Coalition for Epidemic Preparedness Innovations is a notable exception in that it raised a lot of non-ODA funding to support pandemic vaccine development. However, it took a once-in-a-century pandemic to deliver that funding surge, and a GPI-funded institution needs a flow rather than a surge.

    Governments will need to be sure their global institutions can use GPI well, and they will never be sure until somebody builds and operates one. But with only ODA to deploy, it’s hard to see that happening — as the Pandemic Fund experience shows. Catch-22.

    Reply Comment
    • Dear Robin, thank you for sharing your views on this topic – really insightful! I think it would be interesting to take a closer look at the examples you mentioned. Best Stephen

      Reply Comment

Leave a comment